Skip to:Content
|
Bottom
Cover image for Where Keynes went wrong : and why world governments keep creating inflation, bubbles, and busts
Title:
Where Keynes went wrong : and why world governments keep creating inflation, bubbles, and busts
Personal Author:
Physical Description:
vi, 384 pages : 24 cm.
ISBN:
9781604190175

Available:*

Library
Item Barcode
Call Number
Material Type
Item Category 1
Status
Searching...
30000010225982 HB99.7 L48 2009 Open Access Book Advance Management
Searching...
Searching...
30000010225981 HB99.7 L48 2009 Open Access Book Advance Management
Searching...

On Order

Summary

Summary

In responding to the financial crash of 2008, both the Bush Administration and the Obama Administration have relied on prescriptions developed by John Maynard Keynes, the most important economist since Marx. But should we be relying on Keynes? What did Keynes actually say? Did he make his case? Hunter Lewis concludes that he did not. If Keynes was wrong then so are the economic policies of virtually all world governments today.


Reviews 2

Choice Review

In this odd book, Jackson, the founder of a global investment firm, wants to point out where Keynes went wrong. To do this, he opens with eight chapters attempting to summarize "what Keynes really said frequently relying on exact quotations." These are followed by eight chapters wherein the same arguments are restated, discussed, and supposedly rebutted. The last two sections deal with Keynes and his methods of persuasion and the nature of modern Keynesian economics and its potential for harm. The book certainly mines Keynes's writings or, if Jackson cannot find matter there, Robert Skidelsky's biography of Keynes (v.1, CH, Sep'86; v 2, CH, May'94, 31-5019; v. 3, CH, May'02, 39-5300). Generally he does not try to put the quotations in context--a single quotation can be an amalgamation of two separated by several years and dealing with different theoretical systems. The chapters on Keynes conclude that in his General Theory Keynes "intended to deceive or impress" (p. 277). The last chapter on Keynesian economics has more to do with current American preoccupations than with the ideas of someone who died more than 60 years ago. Summing Up: Not recommended. D. E. Moggridge University of Toronto


Library Journal Review

These books bring 20th-century economist John Maynard Keynes into the current economic debate. During the 1930s, Keynes pioneered the concept of governments forcing interest rates low and using deficit spending to stimulate the moribund economy. The work by Clarke (modern history, ret., Cambridge Univ.; The Last Thousand Days of the British Empire) is the most biographical (though none is a true biography), following Keynes from his early life through his role in influencing economic policy during the Great Depression and World War II. Clarke explains Keynes's association with the Bloomsbury Group, his homosexuality, his investing prowess, and how he formulated his theories in response to the economic turbulence of his times. He shows how Keynes was able to change his mind and go in new directions and how he was able to reach out to governments in changing the economic landscape. This is a generally sympathetic portrayal, giving only brief space to Keynes's critics and using academic, but clear, language. Skidelsky (political economy, emeritus, Univ. of Warwick; John Maynard Keynes), author of the major three-volume biography of Keynes, now looks at how studying Keynes could help with both our current crisis and the study of economics in general. After a too brief biographical profile, Skidelsky goes on to explain that much of Keynes's thinking came from his practical involvement with government and investing, which drove Keynes to seek ways in his theoretical musings to stabilize economic markets. Skidelsky skillfully explains how Keynes's views on human behavior, uncertainty, money, and equilibrium formed the basis of his economic theories. He says that modern economists have relied too much on mathematics to predict what Keynes embraced as uncertainty and that Keynes's ideal of economic fairness has merit today when there has been too much emphasis on the raw accumulation of money. Lewis (cofounder, Cambridge Assoc.; How Much Money Does an Economy Need?) sets out to refute Keynesian economics and show that it's what has brought the world to the present crisis. Through paraphrasing and verbatim quotations, he presents Keynes's economic arguments from his The General Theory and other writings and then offers counterarguments. Regarding Keynes's proposition that government needs to regulate fairness in the markets, Lewis asks how government officials influenced by politics can truly make things fairer. Lewis extends the debate to the current crisis and says that the low-interest-rate environment promulgated for years by governments was Keynesian and the very cause of the current credit crisis and recession. In the end, he dismisses Keynes as a promoter of false utopian theories. Lewis has done a service, even if in the negative, of concisely and critically summarizing Keynes's economic theories, and his book will make readers think. VERDICT All three books are useful for understanding Keynes. Clarke's is recommended for those seeking to know more about Keynes as an individual, Skidelsky's is for those wanting to dig deeper into Keynes' economic prescriptions as they relate to today, and Lewis's more contentious work is highly recommended to anyone seeking both to understand and to question Keynesian economics.-Lawrence Maxted, Gannon Univ. Lib., Erie, PA (c) Copyright 2010. Library Journals LLC, a wholly owned subsidiary of Media Source, Inc. No redistribution permitted.


Go to:Top of Page